Attempt Any
Four Case Study
Case Study 1 :
Structuring global companies
As the chapter illustrates, to carry out their
activities in pursuit of their objectives, virtually all organisations adopt some form of
organisational structure. One traditional method of
organisation is to group individuals by function or purpose, using a departmental structure to allocate
individuals to their specialist areas (e.g. Marketing, HRM and so on ). Another is to
group activities by product or service, with each product group normally responsible
for providing its own functional requirements. A
third is to combine the two in the form of a matrix structure with its vertical and horizontal flows of
responsibility and authority, a method of organisation much favoured in
university Business Schools.
What of companies with a global reach: how do
they usually organise them-
selves?
Writing in the Financial Times in November
2000 Julian Birkinshaw, Associate Professor of
Strategic and International Management at London Business School, identifies
four basic models of global company structure:
● The International Division - an arrangement
in which the company establishes a
separate
division to deal
with business outside
its own country.
The
International Division would typically be
concerned with tariff and trade issues,
foreign agents/partners and other aspects
involved in selling overseas. Normally
the division does not make anything itself, it
is simply responsible for interna-
tional sales. This arrangement tends to be
found in medium-sized companies
with limited international sales.
The Global Product Division - a product-based
structure with managers responsible
for their product line globally. The company
is split into a number of global busi-
nesses arranged by product (or service) and
usually overseen by their own
president. It has been a favoured structure
among large global companies such as
BP, Siemens and 3M.
● The Area Division - a geographically based
structure in which the major line of
authority lies with the country (e.g. Germany)
or regional (e.g. Europe) manager who
is responsible for the different product
offerings within her/his geographical area.
● The Global Matrix - as the name suggests a
hybrid of the two previous structural
types. In the global matrix each business
manager reports to two bosses, one
responsible for the global product and one for
the country/region. As we indi-
cated in the previous edition of this book,
this type of structure tends to come
into and go out of fashion. Ford, for example,
adopted a matrix structure in the
later 1990s, while a number of other global
companies were either streamlining
or dismantling theirs (e.g. Shell, BP, IBM).
As Professor Birkinshaw indicates, ultimately
there is no perfect structure and organisations tend
to change their approach over time according to changing circumstances,
fads, the perceived
needs of the
senior executives or the
predispositions of
powerful individuals. This observation is no less true of universities than it
is of traditional businesses.
Case study questions
1.
Professor
Birkinshaw’s article identifies the advantages and disadvantages of being
a global business. What are his major arguments?
2.
In
your opinion what are likely to be the key factors determining how a global company will organise itself?
Case 2 : Resource
prices
As we saw in Chapter 1, resources such as
labour, technology and raw materials
constitute inputs into the production process that are utilised by
organisations to
produce outputs. Apart
from concerns over the quality, quantity and availability of
the different factors of
production, businesses are also interested in the issue of
input prices since these
represent costs to the organisation which ultimately have
to be met from revenues if the business is to survive. As in any other market,
the
prices of economic
resources can change over time for a variety of reasons, most, if
not all, of which are
outside the direct control of business organisations. Such fluc-
tuations in input prices can be illustrated by the following examples:
● Rising labour costs - e.g. rises in wages or
salaries and other labour-related costs
(such as pension contributions or healthcare
schemes) that are not offset by
increases in productivity or changes in
working practices. Labour costs could rise
for a variety of reasons including skills
shortages, demographic pressures, the
introduction of a national minimum wage or
workers seeking to maintain their
living standards in an
inflationary period.
● Rising raw material costs - e.g. caused by
increases in the demand for certain raw
materials and/or shortages (or bottlenecks) in
supply. It can also be the result of
the need to switch to more
expensive raw material sources because of customer
pressure, environmental
considerations or lack of availability.
● Rising energy costs - e.g. caused by demand
and/or supply problems as in the oil
market in recent years, with growth in India
and China helping to push up
demand and coinciding with supply difficulties
linked to events such as the war
in Iraq, hurricanes in the Gulf of Mexico or
decisions by OPEC.
● Increases in the cost of purchasing new
technology/capital equipment - e.g.
caused by the need to compete with rivals or
to meet more stringent government
regulations in areas such as health and safety or the environment.
As the above examples illustrate, rising input
prices can be the result of factors operating at both
the micro and macro level and these can range from events which are linked to natural causes to
developments of a political, social and/or economic kind. While many of these influences in
the business environment are uncontrollable,
there are steps business organisations can (and do) often take to address the issue of rising input prices that
may threaten their competitiveness. Examples include
the following:
● Seeking cheaper sources of labour (e.g. Dyson
moved its production of vacuum
cleaners to the Far East).
● Abandoning salary-linked pension schemes or
other fringe benefits (e.g. com-
pany cars, healthcare provisions, paid
holidays).
● Outsourcing certain activities (e.g. using
call centres to handle customer com-
plaints, or outsourcing services such as security,
catering, cleaning, payroll, etc.). ●
Switching raw materials or energy suppliers (e.g. to take advantage of
discounts
by entering into longer agreements to
purchase).
● Energy-saving measures (e.g. through better
insulation, more regular servicing of
equipment, product and/or
process redesign).
● Productivity gains (e.g. introducing
incentive schemes).
In addition to measures such as these, some
organisations seek cost savings through
divestment of parts of the
business or alternatively through merger or takeover
activity. In the former
case the aim tends to be to focus on the organisation’s core
products/services and to
shed unprofitable and/or costly activities; in the latter the
objective is usually to
take advantage of economies of scale, particularly those asso-
ciated with purchasing, marketing, administration and financing the business.
Case study questions
1. If a company is considering switching production to a country
where wage costs
are lower, what other factors will it need
to take into account before doing so?
2.
Will increased
environmental standards imposed by government on businesses
inevitably result in
higher business costs?
Case 3 :
Government and business - friend or foe?
As we have seen, governments intervene in the
day-to-day working of the economy
in a variety of ways in
the hope of improving the environment in which industrial
and commercial activity
takes place. How far they are successful in achieving this
goal is open to question.
Businesses, for example, frequently complain of over-
interference by
governments and of the burdens
imposed upon them
by
government legislation and
regulation. Ministers, in contrast, tend to stress how
they have helped to create an environment conducive to entrepreneurial activity
through the different policy initiatives and through a supportive legal and
fiscal
regime. Who is right?
While there is no simple answer to this
question, it is instructive to examine the
different surveys which
are regularly undertaken of business attitudes and condi-
tions in different
countries. One such survey by the European Commission - and
reported by Andrew Osborn
in the Guardian on 20 November 2001 - claimed that
whereas countries such as
Finland, Luxembourg, Portugal and the Netherlands
tended to be regarded as
business-friendly, the United Kingdom was perceived as
the most difficult and
complicated country to do business with in the whole of
Europe. Foreign firms
evidently claimed that the UK was harder to trade with than
other countries owing to
its bureaucratic procedures and its tendency to rigidly
enforce business
regulations. EU officials singled out Britain’s complex tax formali-
ties, employment
regulations and product conformity rules as particular problems
for foreign companies -
criticisms which echo those of the CBI and other represen-
tative bodies who have
been complaining of the cost of over-regulation to UK firms
over a considerable number of years.
The news, however, is not all bad. The
Competitive Alternatives study (2002) by
KPMG of costs in various
cities in the G7 countries, Austria and the Netherlands
indicated that Britain is
the second cheapest place in which to do business in the
nine industrial countries
(see www.competitivealternatives.com). The survey, which
looked at a range of
business costs - especially labour costs and taxation -, placed
the UK second behind
Canada world-wide and in first place within Europe. The
country’s strong showing
largely reflected its competitive labour costs, with manu-
facturing costs estimated
to be 12.5 per cent lower than in Germany and 20 per
cent lower than many other
countries in continental Europe. Since firms frequently
use this survey to
identify the best places to locate their business, the data on rela-
tive costs are likely to
provide the UK with a competitive advantage in the battle for
foreign inward investment (see Mini case, above).
Case study questions
1. How
would you account for the difference in perspective between firms who often
complain of government over-interference in business matters and ministers who
claim that they have the
interests of business at heart when taking decisions?
2.
To what extent
do you think that relative costs are the critical factor in determining
inward investment
decisions?
Case 4 : The
end of the block exemption
As we have seen in the chapter, governments
frequently use laws and regulations to promote competition within the marketplace in
the belief that this has significant benefits for the
consumer and for the economy generally. Such interventions occur not only at national level, but also in
situations where governments work together to provide mutual benefits, as in the European
Union’s attempts to set up a ‘Single Market’ across the member states of the
EU.
While few would deny that competitive markets
have many benefits, the search
for increased competition
at national level and beyond can sometimes be
restrained by the
political realities of the situation, a point underlined by a previous
decision of the EU authorities to allow a block exemption from the normal rules
of
competition in the EU car market. Under this system, motor manufacturers
operat-
ing within the EU were permitted to create networks of selective and exclusive dealerships and to engage in certain other
activities normally outlawed under the competition provisions of the single market.
It was argued that the system of selective and exclusive distribution (SED)
benefited consumers by providing them with a cradle-to-grave service, alongside what was
said to be a highly competitive supply situation within the heavily branded
global car market.
Introduced in 1995, and extended until the end
of September 2002, the block
exemption was highly
criticised for its impact on the operation of the car market in
Europe. Following a
critical report by the UK competition authorities in April 2000,
the EU published a review
(in November 2000) of the workings of the existing
arrangement for distributing and servicing cars, highlighting its adverse
conse-
quences for both consumers
and retailers and signalling the need for change. Despite
intensive lobbying by the
major car manufacturers, and by some national govern-
ments, to maintain the
current rules largely intact, the European Commission
announced its intention of
replacing the block exemption regulation when it expired
in September, subject of course to consultation with interested parties.
In essence the Commission’s proposals aimed to
give dealers far more independ-
ence from suppliers by
allowing them to solicit for business anywhere in the EU
and to open showrooms wherever they want; they would also be able to sell cars
supplied by different
manufacturers under the same roof. The plan also sought to
open up the aftersales
market by breaking the tie which existed between sales and
servicing. The proposal
was that independent repairers would in future be able to
get greater access to the
necessary spare parts and technology, thereby encouraging
new entrants to join the market with reduced initial investment costs.
While these proposals were broadly welcomed by
groups representing consumers
(e.g. the Consumer
Association in the UK), some observers felt that the planned
reforms did not go far
enough to weaken the power of the suppliers over the market
(see e.g. the editorial in
the Financial Times, 11 January 2002). For instance it
appeared to be the case
that while manufacturers would be able to supply cars to
supermarkets and other new
retailers, they would not be required by law to do so,
suggesting that a market
free-for-all was highly unlikely to emerge in the foreseeable
future. Equally the
Commission’s plans appeared to do little to protect dealers from
threats to terminate their franchises should there be a dispute with the
supplier.
In the event the old block exemption scheme
expired at the end of September
2002 and the new rules
began the next day. However, the majority of the provisions
under the EC rules did not
come into effect until the following October (2003) and
the ban on ‘location
clauses’ - which limit the geographical scope of dealer opera-
tions - only came into
effect two years later. Since October 2005 dealers have been
free to set up secondary
sales outlets in other areas of the EU, as well as their own
countries. This is
expected to stengthen competition between dealers across the
Single Market to the
advantage of consumers (e.g. greater choice and reduced prices).
Case study questions
1.
Can you suggest
any reasons why the European Commission was willing to grant
the block exemption in the first place, given that it ran counter to its
proposals for
a Single Market?
2.
Why might the
new reforms make cars cheaper for European consumers?
Case 5 : The sale of goods on the
Internet
The sale of consumer goods on the Internet
(particularly those between European member states)
raises a number of legal issues. First, there is the issue of trust, with-
out which the consumer
will not buy; they will need assurance that the seller is genuine, and that they will get the goods that
they believe they have ordered.
Second, there is the issue
of consumer rights with respect to the goods in question: what rights exist and do they vary across
Europe? Last, the issue of enforcement: what happens should anything go wrong?
Information and trust
Europe recognises the problems of doing business across the
Internet or telephone
and it has attempted to address the main stumbling blocks via Directives. The
Consumer Protection (Distance Selling) Regulations 2000 attempts to address the
issues of trust in cross-border consumer sales, which may take place over the
Internet (or telephone). In short, the consumer needs to know quite a bit of
infor-
mation, which they may otherwise have easy access to if they were buying face
to
face. Regulation 7 requires inter alia for the seller to identify themselves
and an
address must be provided if the goods are to be paid for in advance. Moreover,
a
full description of the goods and the final price (inclusive of any taxes) must
also
be provided. The seller must also inform the buyer of the right of cancellation available under Regulations 10-12, where the buyer has a right to
cancel the contract for seven days starting on the day after the consumer
receives the goods or services. Failure to inform the consumer of this right
automatically extends the period to three months. The cost of returning goods
is to be borne by the buyer, and the seller is entitled to deduct the costs
directly flowing from recovery as a restocking fee. All of this places a
considerable obligation on the seller; however, such data should stem many
misunderstandings and so greatly assist consumer faith and confidence in
non-face-to-face sales.
Another concern for the consumer is fraud. The consumer who has
paid by
credit card will be protected by section 83 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974,
under
which a consumer/purchaser is not liable for the debt incurred, if it has been
run
up by a third party not acting as the agent of the buyer. The Distance Selling
Regulations extend this to debit cards, and remove the ability of the card
issuer to
charge the consumer for the first £50 of loss (Regulation 21). Moreover,
section 75
of the Consumer Credit Act 1974 also gives the consumer/buyer a like claim
against
the credit card company for any misrepresentation or breach of contract by the
seller. This is extremely important in a distance selling transaction, where
the seller
may disappear.
What quality and what rights?
The next issue relates to the quality that may be expected from
goods bought over
the Internet. Clearly, if goods have been bought from abroad, the levels of
quality
required in other jurisdictions may vary. It is for this reason that Europe has
attempted to standardise the issue of quality and consumer rights, with the
Consumer Guarantees Directive (1999/44/EC), thus continuing the push to encour-
age cross-border consumer purchases. The implementing Sale and Supply of Goods
to Consumer Regulations 2002 came into force in 2003, which not only lays down
minimum quality standards, but also provides a series of consumer remedies
which
will be common across Europe. The Regulations further amend the Sale of Goods
Act 1979. The DTI, whose job it was to incorporate the Directive into domestic
law
(by way of delegated legislation) ensured that the pre-existing consumer rights
were
maintained, so as not to reduce the overall level of protection available to
con-
sumers. The Directive requires goods to be of ‘normal’ quality, or fit for any
purpose made known by the seller. This has been taken to be the same as our
pre-
existing ‘reasonable quality’ and ‘fitness for purpose’ obligations owed under
sections 14(2) and 14(3) of the Sale of Goods Act 1979. Moreover, the
pre-existing
remedy of the short-term right to reject is also retained. This right provides
the
buyer a short period of time to discover whether the goods are in conformity
with
the contract. In practice, it is usually a matter of weeks at most. After that
time has
elapsed, the consumer now has four new remedies that did not exist before,
which
are provided in two pairs. These are repair or replacement, or price reduction
or
rescission. The pre-existing law only gave the consumer a right to damages,
which
would rarely be exercised in practice. (However, the Small Claims Court would
ensure a speedy and cheap means of redress for almost all claims brought.) Now
there is a right to a repair or a replacement, so that the consumer is not left
with an
impractical action for damages over defective goods. The seller must also bear
the
cost of return of the goods for repair. So such costs must now be factored into
any
business sales plan. If neither of
these remedies is suitable or actioned within a ‘rea-
sonable period
of time’ then the consumer may rely on the second pair of
remedies.
Price reduction permits the consumer to claim back a segment of the pur-
chase price if
the goods are still useable. It is effectively a discount for defective
goods.
Rescission permits the consumer to reject the goods, but does not get a full
refund, as
they would under the short-term right to reject. Here money is knocked
off for
‘beneficial use’. This is akin to the pre-existing treatment for breaches of
durability,
where goods have not lasted as long as goods of that type ought reason-
ably be
expected to last. The level of compensation would take account of the use
that the consumer has (if any) been able to put the goods to and a deduction
made
off the return
of the purchase price. However, the issue that must be addressed is as
to the length
of time that goods may be expected to last. A supplier may state the
length of the
guarantee period, so a £500 television set guaranteed for one year
would have a
life expectancy of one year. On the other hand, a consumer may
expect a television set to last ten years. Clearly, if the set went wrong after
six
months, the
consumer would only get £250 back if the retailer’s figure was used,
but would
receive £475 if their own figure was used. It remains to be seen how this
provision will work in practice.
One problem with distance sales
has been that of liability for goods which arrive
damaged. The
pre-existing domestic law stated that risk would pass to the buyer once
the goods were
handed over to a third-party carrier. This had the major problem in
practice of who would actually be liable for the damage. Carriers would blame
the
supplier and
vice versa. The consumer would be able to sue for the loss, if they were
able to
determine which party was responsible. In practice, consumers usually went
uncompensated
and such a worry has put many consumers off buying goods over the
Internet. The
Sale and Supply of Goods to Consumer Regulations also modify the
transfer of
risk, so that now the risk remains with the seller until actual delivery. This
will clearly
lead to a slight increase in the supply of goods to consumers, with the
goods usually
now being sent by insured delivery. However, this will avoid the prob-
lem of who is actually liable and should help to boost confidence.
Enforcement
Enforcement for domestic sales is
relatively straightforward. Small-scale consumer
claims can be
dealt with expeditiously and cheaply under the Small Claims Court.
Here claims
under £5000 for contract-based claims are brought in a special court
intended to
keep costs down by keeping the lawyers’ out of the court room, as a vic-
torious party
cannot claim for their lawyers’ expenses. The judge will conduct the
case in a more
‘informal’ manner, and will seek to discover the legal issues by ques-
tioning both parties, so no formal knowledge of the law is required. The total
cost of
such a case, even if it is lost, is the cost of issuing the proceedings
(approximately
10 per cent of the value claimed)
and the other side’s ‘reasonable expenses’. Expenses
must be kept
down, and a judge will not award value which has been deliberately run
up, such
first-class rail travel and stays in five star hotels. Residents of Northampton
have hosted a
trial of an online claims procedure, so that claims may now be made
via the
Internet. (www.courtservice.gov.uk outlines the procedure for MCOL,
or
Money Claims
Online.) Cases will normally be held in the defendant’s court, unless the
complainant is a consumer and the defendant a business.
Enforcement is the weak point in the European
legislation, for there is, as yet, no
European-wide Small Claims
Court dealing with transnational European transac-
tions. The consumer is
thus forced to contemplate expensive civil action abroad in a
foreign language, perhaps
where no such small claims system exists - a pointless
measure for all but the
most expensive of consumer purchases. The only redress lies
in EEJ-Net, the European
Extra-Judicial Network, which puts the complainant in
touch with any applicable
professional or trade body in the supplier’s home member
state. It does require the
existence of such a body, which is unlikely if the transac-
tion is for electrical
goods, which is one of the most popular types of Internet
purchase. Therefore, until
Europe provides a Euro Small Claims Court, the consumer
cross-border buyer may
have many rights, but no effective means of enforcement.
Until then it would appear
that section 75 of the Consumer Credit Act 1974, which
gives the buyer the same
remedies against their credit card company as against the
seller, is the only
effective means of redress.
Case study questions
1. Consider the checklist of data which a
distance seller must provide to a consumer
purchaser. Is this
putting too heavy a burden on sellers?
2. Is a consumer distance buyer any better off
after the European legislation?
3. Are there any remaining issues that must be tackled to increase
European cross-
border consumer trade?
No comments:
Post a Comment